Why are family-run firms prospering while traditional professionally-run multinational corporations are failing? David Birnbaum suggests the best examples of the contrast between the two are to be found within the global garment industry.

In 1606 the British Government granted a charter to the Virginia Company of London – thus creating the world’s first publicly listed multinational corporation, while at the same time beginning a 400-year debate between family firm and professionally-run corporations.

This was the age of enlightenment, and the joint-stock company became the vehicle of change, particularly in the economic sphere. Professional managers were rapidly taking over from family control. Equally important, where capital investment had previously been in the hands of a few wealthy families, the joint-stock company opened ownership to a much wider segment of the population.

The arguments favouring the joint-stock company with its professional management and popular ownership against the traditional family firm go on today. The fundamentals remain the same, only the tools have changed.

Today’s debate is all about productivity and has two factors:

  • Productivity is one of the most important underlying factors for business and economic success. On the microeconomic level, increased productivity for a company reduces costs, which allows for both rising wages and increased profits. On the macroeconomic level, increased productivity leads to greater economic expansion and higher GDP.
  • Professionally-run corporations consistently show greater productivity than family-run enterprises.

Herein lies the problem. On the one hand, the two factors are indeed true:  

GlobalData Strategic Intelligence

US Tariffs are shifting - will you react or anticipate?

Don’t let policy changes catch you off guard. Stay proactive with real-time data and expert analysis.

By GlobalData
  • Yes, the ability to increase productivity is crucial to the success of both the company and the national economy. And
  • Yes, when it comes to increased productivity, the professionally-run corporation is a more efficient vehicle than the family business.
  • However, as is sometimes the case, philosophy and reality may not coincide.

We should ask a simple pertinent question: If the family firm is not as efficient and in other ways inferior to the professionally-run corporation, why then do family businesses continue to flourish?

The global garment industry

The best example of the contrast between the family firm and the professionally-run corporation lies with our own sleeve-and-shouldpad industry.

On the supplier side almost all of the major factories are family firms. But on the customer side we have a sharp divide, where almost all the major US brands and retailers are professionally-run corporations, while almost all the European and Asian brands and retailers have gone the other way.

The US side
It has become self-evident, that to an increasingly larger degree, the big factories are better capitalised and more secure than their major US customers.

We can see the difference when we look at the number of major retailers that are going broke compared with the negligible number of major factories facing serious problems.

We can see the difference when we consider that of the US retailers, Walmart, a family firm, remains the strongest and most profitable.

The other side
Outside the US, the major retailers and brands have gone in a different direction.

There are two similar groups:

  • Family firms such as C&A, Otto, Uniqlo, H&M and Max Mara.
  • Founder controlled companies such as Inditex, Arcadia, LVMH, Kering and Primark, to name a few.

These companies, while facing many of the current industry problems, are still doing well. More to the point, US subsidiary operations are doing much better than their US domestic competitors.

The new 400 year debate

Why has the family firm prospered while the professionally-run multinational corporation failed? What are the similarities? What are the differences?

Similarities
During the past decades, family firms have taken on some of the tools of the professionally-run corporation:

  • To bring in more capital, many of the larger family firms have become publicly listed capital;
  • To bring in more talent, many family firms have brought in professional managers.

However, despite these changes, family firms have retained complete control either by limiting the percent of shares available to the public, or by retaining voting shares to the family.

The major differences

  • Core competency: The family firm is run by family members, all of whom have specific knowledge of the work of the firm. For example, the family-run garment company is run by garment specialists, while the professionally-run garment corporation may be run by professional managers who often rely on subordinates to understand what the corporation does and how it does it.
  • Organisational stability: In the family firm, those running the company have jobs for life, while those below are also relatively immune from problem periods. This is true particularly in East Asia where loyalty counts for much. The professionally-run corporation is far more “pragmatic,” where downsizing at all levels occurs even in periods of short term decline.

This gives rise two very different cultures:
1: The family firm values new ideas and particularly the people willing to express those ideas. They recognise that those who constantly say NO to new ideas are never wrong because they take no responsibility, with the result that the company develops a culture defined as: If you do not make mistakes, you are not doing your job.  
2: The staff of the professionally-run corporation, particularly management, recognise that they cannot afford even a single failure and therefore cannot risk presenting or even supporting new ideas. They are living in a one-strike-you’re-out environment, with the result that the company becomes permeated with a culture of CMA (cover my ass).

  • Long term strategies vs short term fixes: The family firm can afford to make investments that may not become profitable for many years, while the professionally-run corporation must concentrate on very short term results (i.e., quarterly profit).
  • The shareholder-value myth: Imagine you own a company. Since you own all the shares, increasing shareholder value is synonymous with increasing the value of your company. You have four ways to increase shareholder value:

1: Innovation through research and development;
2: Increase company asset;
3: Increase sales volume;
4: Increase profit margins.

Now imagine you are the CEO of a multinational corporation. In your one-strike-you’re-out world, you cannot afford failed investments. Actually in your world, where success is measured in quarterly profits, you cannot afford any investments. For you, increasing shareholder value is limited to a series of fixes:

1: Reduce all expenses that do not result in short-term quantifiable benefit, with R&D being the first to go. Cancelling R&D will save money at no cost, albeit in the short term. However, in the long term, without R&D there may be no long term.  
2: Share buybacks. By buying back your company shares you automatically increase the value of the remaining shares, albeit at the expense of reducing your company’s assets.
3: Sale of profitable divisions. By selling off profitable divisions, you automatically increase cash holdings, albeit at the expense of reducing future profits.
4: Downsizing during difficult periods. By firing staff and workers, you reduce overhead costs, albeit by losing what is probably your greatest capital asset ? your people. When downsizing is voluntary, the best people will take the money and run, knowing they can find employment elsewhere. When downsizing is involuntary, your best people will still be out looking for new jobs simply as a matter of self-protection.

To a degree, your fixes work. But you are only achieving short-term benefits while destroying the long-term value of your company.

On the macroeconomic level the situation looks even worse, particularly in the United States.

Where once the US was the world innovation leader, as of 2018, according to the Bloomberg Innovation index, the US no longer ranks in the top 10. The reasons are obvious:

  • Government has cut R&D subsidies to the bone, while at the same time deporting many qualified scientists and technicians, in many cases including those trained in the US;
  • Universities in the US are no longer the equal of those located in Canada, Europe and Asia;
  • The traditional Corporations have cut R&D investment to the bone;
  • The new model corporations are moving R&D out of the US to Canada, Europe and Asia.

The traditional professionally-run corporations have found that investment in government produces the best return without the need to provide increased value.

  • Persuading government to increase tariffs on competitive imports such as steel, solar energy panels, washing machines;
  • Persuading government to ban imports of competitive products such as pharmaceuticals from Canada;
  • Persuading government to create laws to benefit corporations unfairly, such as ending new neutrality and preventing citizens from taking legal action against arms manufacturers complicit in attacks on school children;
  • Allowing corporations to cause ecological damage by allowing increased offshore oil exploration; leaving the Paris Accord on global warming.

These and many more have brought about the greatest tax increase in history. I am not referring to the recent 2017 Tax Reform Reconciliation Act, but to the indirect taxes whereby every benefit granted to the corporations will come directly out of consumers’ pockets in the form of higher retail prices.

Where do we go from here?

While many leading industry professionals are still living in the 17th century age of enlightenment, there are some who are looking at the world as it exists today and are working to move into the here-and-now.

The internet has brought more than a revolution in technology. It has brought a new revolutionary business developed by Amazon, Facebook, Google and others.

These new-model companies have moved away from the short-term fixes of the traditional professionally-run corporation in favour of the family-firm model. The main difference is that while the family firm is controlled by the family, the new model companies are in their first generation, so control still rests with the founders.  

Other than that, the new model company characteristics closely follow the family firm:

  • Core competency;
  • Organisational stability;
  • Constant adoption of new ideas;
  • Long-term strategies;
  • Rejection of shareholder value as the main strategic force.

The new-model companies have started a new debate between them and the traditional professionally-run corporations. And while it is still early days, it appears that the new-model companies have already won.